Lebanon’s rigid consociationalism

Lebanon adopted a consociational approach to governance in its early days of contemporary state formation.[9] Sectarianism became an institution that turned into a ‘socially-constructed reality’ with the passage of time.[10] Lebanon’s political framework placed sectarianism at the heart of all facets of political life: political representation; justice and security; and access to resources.[11] This framework was formalised in 1989, when a Saudi-led effort brokered the Taif Accord to end the civil war. The Accord guaranteed power sharing through religious institutions – 11 officially recognised sects were to be represented in the government’s legislative and executive branches, with separate personal status laws and courts for each.[12] A proportional number of high-level government offices, cabinet seats (including ministries up to the level of secretary-general and general-director), parliamentary positions, judicial council members, and public sector jobs were reserved for representatives of each religious community.[13] Under Taif, positions are shared equally between Christian and Muslim sects, replacing the earlier 1943 National Pact, which favoured Christians by a ratio of 6:5.

The new constitution also shifted executive power from the Maronite President to the Council of Ministers, presided over by a Sunni Muslim prime minister and administered by a Shi’a Speaker of Parliament. However, the balance of power is guaranteed by veto power granted to all three major political communities through the three ‘presidencies’ (the prime minister, speaker of the parliament and president), forming a ‘Triumvirate or Troika’.[14] The objective of this mutual veto system is to ensure that different political communities can protect their interests and must cooperate to enable meaningful governmental decision making.

Once in power, however, mutual vetoes coupled with superficial interconfessional alliances led more often to stalemate and inoperability than to good governance and cooperation. This undermined executive decision making by making it difficult to garner consensus for contentious decisions. An example of such stalemate is the presidential vacuum that occurred between 2014 and 2016 as political factions struggled to elect a new president. A standoff ensued that effectively paralysed the country for over two years, since the president appoints a prime minister to form a government. The decision to elect Michel Aoun as president came after an agreement was reached between him and Saad Hariri. Few details are known about the terms of the deal, apart from a pledge to appoint Hariri as PM in exchange for him dropping his opposition to Aoun’s candidacy.[15] The executive branch is approved by parliament and the presidency, and reflects parliament’s power-sharing model as well as featuring representation of different sectarian groups. This has produced conflicts of interest between the legislature and executive that have paralysed the executive. A good example is Hassan Diab’s ‘government of specialists’, which came into being as the result of another bout of haggling by Lebanon’s ruling elites. After failing to implement reform policies – which were continuously rejected in parliament – Diab’s cabinet resigned once it became clear that, to protect party interests, parliament was refusing an independent investigation into the Beirut port blast.

On top of elite scheming to retain as much control as possible, the rigid sectarian quotas in both elected and non-elected public offices are unresponsive to demographic change. This means that the representativeness of sectarian elites is not necessarily as solid as it might look. For example, having undergone rapid demographic growth since the 1970s, Lebanon still maintains political representation based on its population census of 1932. As a result, the number of non-Christian seats in parliament is equal to that of Christians, even though Christians were estimated to total 38.2 per cent of voters and Muslims 61.6 per cent in 2011.[16] This means that certain electoral constituencies are under-represented while others are over-represented.[17] In short, by making organic change difficult (e.g. by allocating offices and resources based on regular independent population censuses), sectarian communities are in permanent competition to find loopholes and backdoors in the electoral system to achieve larger representation and political gains.

One way of doing this is by manipulating electoral laws to garner cross-confessional seats and control a larger proportion of parliament than the allotted sectarian quota. For example, Christian seats in southern electoral districts are elected by the majority Shi’a population and considered the Shi’as’ Christian seats. Such issues have been a source of contestation and explain why the previous parliament postponed national elections three times in five years as factions could not agree on an electoral law.

Strong symbolic narratives underpin such power distribution and conservation mechanisms. The Christians continuously refer to ‘preserving’ political power in order to mobilise their constituency because if Lebanon’s demographic shifts were reflected in the country’s electoral system, they would spell a loss of Christian influence. Simultaneously, Muslims have capitalised on under-representation in government to institutionalise a discourse of marginalisation and a narrative of staying relevant. In the 2018 parliamentary election, none of the confessional political parties ran with a policy programme but instead relied on the discourse of preserving sectarian identities. For example, the Lebanese Forces party more than doubled its seats from 2009 by positioning itself as the champion of Christian values and influence. Its success reflects how this discourse resonates with Lebanon’s Christian population,[18] while diverting attention away from good governance and effective party performance. Between 2009 and 2017, parliament failed to address citizens’ needs and priorities – with only 9 per cent of laws passed addressing socioeconomic concerns.[19] In fact, MPs have a different set of priorities than citizens. While 58 per cent of citizens highlighted socioeconomic challenges – such as unemployment, price increases, health, education, electricity, and water – as their main concerns, only 30 per cent of MPs shared these concerns.[20] Completing this paradox, in May 2018 almost half of Lebanon’s electorate voted for the same political parties as they had in 2009. Perhaps, inadvertently, they showcased the robustness of sectarian politics.[21]

Iraq’s incomplete consociationalism

In many respects, since 2003 Iraq’s political system has evolved along similar lines to Lebanon’s consociational democracy.[22] The new constitution, ratified in 2005, stressed that ‘Iraq is a country of multiple nationalities, religions, and sects’.[23] Unlike Lebanon’s corporate consociational system, which accommodates groups according to predetermined sectarian or ethnic criteria, Iraq’s liberal consociational system is based on democratic preferences.[24] As such, the principle of sectarian proportionality is not constitutionally enshrined. Article 49 of the Constitution states merely that ‘representation of all components of the people shall be upheld in parliament’. In practice, however, Iraqi consociationalism began to generate patterns and discourses similar to Lebanon’s, with the dominant positions of state being filled by Iraq’s main communities: the presidency by the Kurds, prime minister by the Shias, and the house speaker by the Sunnis.[25] The need to represent all communities extended beyond top-level appointments and the Iraqi government through the muhasasa system – the distribution of jobs between particular parties and coalitions within a given ethno-sectarian group based on a points system.[26] It should be noted, however, that Iraq’s consociational democracy centres on inclusive ethno-sectarian representation (distribution of posts) much more than on inclusive ethno-sectarian decision making (distribution of power). This means that both majority and minority groups can be excluded and allows for significant concentrations of real power that risk undoing any benefits of consociational governance. As with Lebanon, it generates serious challenges to the business of adequate public governance.[27] Below, we discuss three key mechanisms in Iraqi governance that can work to exclude other groups from power, despite their representation in government or the administration.

The first issue is that, according to article 76 (1) of the Iraqi constitution, the majority bloc has the right to form a government. This is followed by a confidence vote in the prime minister designate, which requires only an absolute parliamentary majority as per article 76 (4). These two provisions are non-consociational. First, the very fact that the largest bloc is automatically designated to nominate a PM undermines the need for bargaining between elites in a deeply divided society. However, since there is ambiguity as to how the largest bloc is designated, there is plenty of horse-trading to agree on criteria and procedure. In the last two elections (2014 and 2018), especially, this has involved cross-sectarian collusion.

Second, the possibility of winning a confidence vote by an absolute majority is problematic from a conscociational point of view because it implies that a major political group may form a coalition government with a number of insignificant groups and exclude other major ones. In practice, even absolute majorities are a tall order given the fragmentation of Iraq’s political blocs. The process of fragmentation has been witnessed in every electoral round since grand coalitions (now defunct) were formed in the 2005 elections. A compromise – the so-called Erbil Agreement – was reached in 2010, under which the main political parties agreed to form a grand coalition at the executive level with an understanding that ministries would be distributed among the main parties. Accordingly, Iraqiya (a coalition consisting of the Sunni National Dialogue Front, Shi’ite Ayad Allawi, and new nationalists) expected to receive the Ministry of Defence and the presidency of the Security Committee, while Maliki received the premiership. Nevertheless, after the formation of the government and parliament’s vote of confidence, Maliki renounced his commitment to the Erbil Agreement and turned down all the candidates that Iraqiya proposed.

A third issue arising from posts being shared on a sectarian basis, but power being exercised on a non-sectarian basis, is the broad authority it affords the prime minister. The constitution allows the PM to exercise wide-ranging executive powers, direct the general policy of the state, control Iraq’s security forces, and preside over the council of ministers.[28] The PM’s power is increased because communities and individual ministers have no executive veto, and there is no quorum to hold a cabinet session or take decisions. Moreover, the president and the PM can dismiss ministers if they do not follow the rules or carry out the wishes of the PM.[29]

This has had two serious effects on Iraqi politics. First, it enables the PM to engage in substantial abuse with potentially devastating effects. For example, during his five-year term as prime minister, Maliki built a personal power base in the security establishment and bolstered the electoral prospects of his Da’wah Party.[30] Secondly, such a concentration of power increases political competition for the office of PM, making forming a post-election coalition more difficult. Because Iraq uses a system of proportional representation, no one party is ever likely to gain a majority in an election. Therefore, a process of cross-party coalition building follows every election. In these negotiations, all parties compete for the position of prime minister because it is seen as the only position that matters. This zero-sum game leaves the country vulnerable to political instability after every election.

In recent years, political blocs have opted for a compromise ‘weak’ prime minister, one who does not threaten the interests of any of the large blocs. Adel Abdel-Mahdi, for example, was a compromise candidate between Sadr’s Sairoun and Ameri’s Fateh parliamentary blocs. Similarly, PM Mustafa al-Kadhimi is a compromise between the Kurds, Sunnis, and Shi’as’ parliamentary blocs. The result is a weak government and a weak PM, neither or which have sufficient support from the political blocs and parties to counter corruption and attempt real reform.

Interim conclusion

The consociational systems of both Iraq and Lebanon demonstrate how political elites in both countries have developed a system that creates and maintains control over the main levers of governance on a sectarian basis. The key problem is less the fact that the state is ruled by an oligarchy, or by a consensus between sects, but rather that no one really rules. The state as a set of institutions is run by a semi-opportunistic collusive-cum-competitive interaction between various parties that emerged from conflict. All parties continuously deploy all possible means to keep the others in check via control over public resources and public institutions while jealously guarding their own prerogatives and social autonomy. Paralysis is both a feature and an output of the political system, in which self-preservation is valued over the need for reform. Sectarian mechanisms are valued above all else because it allows established parties continuous control over political processes and enables resource appropriation. The logic of sectarian-based power sharing produces lengthy political stalemates almost by default and makes long-term decision making a Herculean task. Typically, this leads to weak governments with limited political autonomy that are incapable of adequate public performance, let alone of innovating the state.

Lebanon’s consociationalism has two origins: first, episodes of peasant uprisings and communal strife in Mount Lebanon from 1820 to 1960; second, the partition of the region between the British and the French.
Luckmann, T and Berger, P, 1991. The Social Construction of Reality, London: Penguin Books.
Salloukh, B F, et al., 2015. The Politics of Sectarianism in Postwar Lebanon, London: Pluto Books.
The Taif Accord established two objectives for postwar parliamentary elections: mutual, peaceful coexistence between the different confessional groups (al-aysh al-mushtarak) and their proper political representation (al-tamthil al-siyasi).
Saliba, I, 2010. Lebanon: Constitutional law and the political rights of religious communities. Library of Congress 12: 1–8. link (accessed 15 July 2020); Calfat, N. 2018. ‘The Frailities of Lebanese Democracy: Outcomes and Limits of the Confessional Framework’. Contexto Internacional 40(2): 269–293.
Johnson, M, 2001. All Honourable Men: The Social Origins of War in Lebanon. London: IB Tauris; Majed, Z, 2010. Hezbollah and the Shiite community: From political confessionalization to confessional specialization. Aspen Institute 11: 1–28.
In Lebanon, a newly elected president appoints a prime minister following consultation with MPs.
Izady, M, 2016. ‘Lebanon ethnic composition’. The Gulf Project 2000. Columbia School of International and Public Affairs. link (accessed15 July 2020); Lebanese Information Center, LIC (LB), 2013. The Lebanese Demographic Reality. Washington, DC: LIC link (accessed 15 July 2020).
Lebanese Association for Democratic Elections, LADE (LB), 2015. Vote Power Data Maps. Beirut. link (accessed 15 July 2020).
Majdi, K. 2018. ‘لماذا تفوق القوات اللبنانية؟’ Alhurra online (accessed 15 July 2020).
Lebanese Center for Policy Studies. 2018. ‘ هل قام النواب بواجباتهم؟’ link (accessed 15 July 2020); Equivalent to 31 laws, 21 of which are loan agreements.
Atallah, S, 2018. ‘Addressing Citizens’ Concerns is not on the Parliament’s Agenda’, Lebanese Centre for Policy Studies (LCPS). link (accessed 15 July 2020).
Arnous, M, 2018. ‘The Robustness of Sectarian Politics in Lebanon: Reflections on the 2018 Elections’, Civil Society Knowledge Centre, Lebanon Support. link (accessed 15 July 2020).
Consociationalism is typically associated with the work of Arend Lijphart, who outlines four core features of the model: government by grand coalition or executive power sharing, veto rights for the different groups, proportionality, and a high degree of autonomy for each segment. See: Lijphart, A, 1977. Democracies in Plural Societies: A Comparative Exploration, New Haven: Yale University Press.
Constitution of Iraq, 2005. link (accessed 15 July 2020).
McGarry, J and O’Leary, B, 2007. ‘Iraq’s Constitution of 2005: Liberal consociation as political prescription’, International Journal of Constitutional Law 5(4) 670–698.
Power sharing also extends beyond high politics to public service appointments in Iraq. Although not by design, the Federal Supreme Court has an overrepresentation of minority judges. The Iraqi army, for example, is roughly made up of 60 per cent Shi’a, 20 per cent Sunni Arabs, and 18 per cent Kurds, reflecting the assumed proportions in Iraqi society at large.
Al-Shaheedi, H, Van Veen, E, 2020. Iraq’s Adolescent Democracy: Where to go from here, The Hague: The Clingendael Institute.
Plans for extra-constitutional institutions such as the Political Council of National Security, the Federal Oil and Gas Council, and the National Council of High Policies, which could be seen as attempts to create additional consociational layers in Iraq’s power-sharing democracy did not go far. Visser, R, 2012. ‘The emasculation of government ministries in consociational democracies: The case of Iraq’, International Journal of Contemporary Iraqi Studies 6 (2) 231-242.
Constitution of Lebanon (Article 17); Constitution of Iraq (Article 78). In contrast, the president is described by the Constitution as simply a ‘symbol of the unity of the country’ (Article 67) with the power to issue pardons, ratify international treaties, award medals and accredit ambassadors (Article 73).
Nonetheless, dismissing the minister requires the consent of the Council of Representatives by an absolute majority (article 68a: Constitution of Iraq). Given that the prime minister is selected from the biggest parliamentary bloc, this is unlikely to pose too much constraint.
He took security decisions without consulting the cabinet for authorisation, including unilaterally forming personal intelligence and military units outside the jurisdiction of the Ministry of Defence and the Ministry of Interior. Maliki also created tribal-support councils in provinces across Iraq that were seen as Dawah party tools for controlling and influencing local populations. Gompert, D., Terrence, K., and Watkins, J., 2010. Security in Iraq: a framework for analyzing emerging threats as U.S. Forces leave, Rand Cooperation.